Economists are fond of pointing out the attractive welfare outcomes of the perfectly competitive model. Of course, economists also concern themselves with analyzing various forms of market failure. One easy example of a market failure is the monopoly outcome. However, it is quite possible to find market failure in industries that look like they should be competitive but somehow end up with less than stellar welfare outcomes.
One such outcome is known as the Common Pool Resource problem. It arises in situations where there is no market mechanism to exclude agents from accessing and utilizing a valuable resource. To illustrate, consider a 1956 movie called Giant, set around the great oil boom in the East Texas oil fields. (Giant was nominated for 10 Academy Awards including Best Picture, 2 Best Actor in a Leading Role nominations (James Dean and Rock Hudson), Best Director, etc. It won just one, the Best Director.) The James Dean character discovers oil on a small plot of land he owned in an area that was used exclusively as cattle range. He built a derrick on his land and started making a great deal of money extracting and selling oil.
However, he only owned a small piece of land overtop a large
LARGE reservoir of oil. He went about
acquiring more land, but lots of other people owned plots of land overtop other
areas of this giant reservoir of oil.
And, they all started constructing their own derricks. Think of the incentive. The oil in the reservoir is finite; every
gallon of oil your rival pulls out is one less gallon for you to extract. So, not only do you want your derrick to run
24 by 7, you want to put as many derricks on your physical plot of land that
you can; the more pipes you can stick
down into that oil reservoir, the more gallons of the fixed pool of oil will
end up belonging to you. In the case of
the East Texas oil fields, it soon looked like this:
(C) B. Anthony Steward/The National Geographic/Christie's Images
The problem arises because too many derricks are pumping out
the oil too fast. Geologists can show
you the models that describe an optimal extraction rate, one that would use the
natural pressure from surrounding aquifers to push the oil up in the cheapest
manner. By sticking thousands of straws
down in the reservoir and sucking as hard as you can on your straw, the
aquifers pushed in too rapidly, leaving vast quantities of oil stuck in hidden
pools and fissures that were inaccessible.
This outcome was very inefficient.
This is the nature of Common Pool Resource problems and the resulting
market failure.
Recently, the January 30, 2013 issue of the New York Times had an Op-Ed by Callum
Roberts titled “Keep the Fishing Ban in New England.” The article discusses a
phenomenon similar to the oilfield disaster described above but occurring in
the great fishing beds off the coast of New England. Again, the common pool problem arose. The sea was full of fish but if any one
fisherman showed restraint in extracting fish, the other fishers would simply
get a larger share of the finite pool of fish below the surface. The result was over-fishing, just as the
oilfield saw over-extraction of the oil. Every fishing firm had an incentive to
fish with as many boats and as many nets as possible to get a larger share of
the fish swimming below the surface. The
result was disastrous, as the stocks got dangerously low.
Policy makers have shown a willingness to intervene in
market transactions when they feel that some group will be impacted by the
transaction but that very same group does not have power to be heard in the
negotiations. For example, consider a
housing developer offering a farmer on the edge of the community enough money
that the farmer agrees to sell her cornfield to the developer. This appears to be a very efficient and
desirable transaction; both the buyer and the seller voluntarily agree to a
transaction that brings both of them some gain. However, if it turns out that
putting houses on the former cornfield would destroy the natural habitat of a small
wetlands creature, policy makers might consider intervention to stop this form
of urban sprawl.
Economists have noted the increasing pressure to have a
third-party agency join in transactions in order to have “…someone who will
speak for the XXX…” where you can substitute
the XXX with “spotted owl” or “grizzly bears” or whatever animal that is being
disadvantaged as a result of a willing and voluntary transaction between two
entities. My favorite quote in the Times
story on the New England fishing issue is:
Federal
law delegated to the New England Fishery Management Council authority to manage
the fishery from 3 miles to 200 miles off the coast, but the council didn’t see
its job as speaking up for fish.
No comments:
Post a Comment